Managing America: The
Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith, how wealth is created
Smith studied moral philosophy at the University of Glasgow
and Oxford University. After graduating, he delivered a successful series of
public lectures at Edinburgh, leading him to collaborate with David Hume during
the Scottish Enlightenment. Smith obtained a professorship at Glasgow teaching
moral philosophy, and during this time he wrote and published The Theory of
Moral Sentiments.
It is true, indeed, that Alexander Hamilton was too
broad-minded to maintain an economic and financial doctrine without any
qualifications, for he only possessed an historical spirit that led him to the
general teaching of a political economy by Adam Smith.
Was Adam Smith the original capitalist?
The answer is not a difficult one.
For instance, it would be fool hardy to state that Adam
Smith was the first political economist in classic antiquity, what of
Aristotle, Democritus, and Varro, but one will find economic theories from both
to his English and to his French predecessors.
Based on Hamilton’s own writings we now know exactly the
extent of his findings are indeed from Adam Smith, for one is able to compare
the same economic views that are contained in Adam Smith’s lecture course in
1763 and his book The Wealth of Nations printed in 1776.
The two fundamental ideas of The Wealth of Nations are those
of self-interest and natural liberty. It was by utilizing and applying these
doctrines to his analysis of economic institutions that Adam Smith achieved his
great success.
"It is not from
the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker," he tells us,"
that we expect our dinner, but from their regard of their own interest. We
address ourselves not to their humanity, but to their self-love, and never talk
to them of our own necessities, but of their advantage."
In the first place, Hamilton borrowed from Smith the
emphasis laid upon interests of the consumers and producers, whereas others
only the interests of the producers.
Secondly, the entire theory of distribution and
manufacturing by Adam Smith, with a division of the produce into rent, wages,
and interest, is based upon the Physiocratic analysis, which Hamilton uses in
his ideas about expanding American manufacturing.
Thirdly, Adam Smith’s theory of the nature and movement of
stock or capital taken from the French writers, which led Hamilton’s writing
concerning the development of an American National Banking System.
And finally, while Adam Smith did not accept the
Physiocratic doctrine of the sole productivity of land, he was induced by them
to make his not entirely fortunate distinction between productive and
unproductive labour in general, which was also included in Hamilton’s writings.
Reduced to the simplest terms, however, it may be said that
Adam Smith was the first great theorist of that stage of capitalist enterprise
which we call the domestic system.
The economists of earlier times were unable to give an
analysis of economic life which is at all satisfactory to us, because the
economic institutions then were different.
However, Smith's thoughts were formed on the threshold of
the English industrial revolution. In 1758 James Brindley built the first canal
between Liverpool and Manchester. In 1769 the barber Arkwright rediscovered
Wyatt's method of roller spinning. In 1770 Hargreaves perfected the spinning
jenny. In 1776 Crompton patented his mule founded on the water frame and in
1765 Watt discovered the use of steam as a motive power. England was fast
losing her agricultural characteristics and getting to be an industrial
country, which is what Hamilton was seeking to develop in America.
Capitalist enterprise
was in its first stage and Adam Smith was its earliest interpreter.
We now have a series of interviews with Adam Smith that
influenced Hamilton’s ideas for the development of American enterprise, the
basis for the Federal government’s ability to levy taxes.
Mr. Smith: To enhance
a nation’s wealth; can you provide your thoughts on the first settlement of the
different European colonies in America?
Adam Smith: The interest which occasioned the first
settlement of the different European colonies in America and the West Indies
was not altogether so plain and distinct as that which directed the
establishment of those of ancient Greece and Rome.
All the different
states of ancient Greece possessed, each of them, but a very small territory,
and when the people in any one of them multiplied beyond what that territory
could easily maintain, a part of them were sent in quest of a new habitation in
some remote and distant part of the world; the warlike neighbours who
surrounded them on all sides, rendering it difficult for any of them to enlarge
very much its territory at home.
The colonies of the
Dorians resorted chiefly to Italy and Sicily, which, in the times preceding the
foundation of Rome, were inhabited by barbarous and uncivilised nations: those
of the Ionians and Eolians, the two other great tribes of the Greeks, to Asia
Minor and the islands of the Egean Sea, of which the inhabitants seem at that
time to have been pretty much in the same state as those of Sicily and Italy.
The mother city, though she considered the colony as a child, at all times
entitled to great favour and assistance, and owing in return much gratitude and
respect, yet considered it as an emancipated child over whom she pretended to
claim no direct authority or jurisdiction.
The colony settled its
own form of government, enacted its own laws, elected its own magistrates, and
made peace or war with its neighbours as an independent state, which had no
occasion to wait for the approbation or consent of the mother city. Nothing can
be more plain and distinct than the interest which directed every such
establishment.
Rome, like most of the
other ancient republics, was originally founded upon an Agrarian law which
divided the public territory in a certain proportion among the different
citizens who composed the state. The course of human affairs by marriage, by
succession, and by alienation, necessarily deranged this original division, and
frequently threw the lands, which had been allotted for the maintenance of many
different families, into the possession of a single person.
Smith continued: To remedy this disorder, for such it was
supposed to be, a law was made restricting the quantity of land which any
citizen could possess to five hundred jugera, about three hundred and fifty
English acres. This law, however, though we read of its having been executed
upon one or two occasions, was either neglected or evaded, and the inequality
of fortunes went on continually increasing.
The greater part of
the citizens had no land, and without it the manners and customs of those times
rendered it difficult for a freeman to maintain his independency.
In the present times,
though a poor man has no land of his own, if he has a little stock he may
either farm the lands of another, or he may carry on some little retail trade;
and if he has no stock, he may find employment either as a country labourer or
as an artificer.
But among the ancient
Romans the lands of the rich were all cultivated by slaves, who wrought under
an overseer who was likewise a slave; so that a poor freeman had little chance
of being employed either as a farmer or as a labourer.
All trades and
manufactures too, even the retail trade, were carried on by the slaves of the
rich for the benefit of their masters, whose wealth, authority, and protection
made it difficult for a poor freeman to maintain the competition against them.
The citizens, therefore, who had no land, had scarce any other means of
subsistence but the bounties of the candidates at the annual elections.
The tribunes, when
they had a mind to animate the people against the rich and the great, put them
in mind of the ancient division of lands, and represented that law which restricted
this sort of private property as the fundamental law of the republic.
The people became
clamorous to get land, and the rich and the great, we may believe, were
perfectly determined not to give them any part of theirs. To satisfy them in
some measure, therefore, they frequently proposed to send out a new colony.
But conquering Rome
was, even upon such occasions, under no necessity of turning out her citizens
to seek their fortune, if one may say so, through the wide world, without
knowing where they were to settle. She assigned them lands generally in the
conquered provinces of Italy, where, being within the dominions of the
republic, they could never form any independent state; but were at best but a
sort of corporation, which, though it had the power of enacting bye-laws for
its own government, was at all times subject to the correction, jurisdiction,
and legislative authority of the mother city.
The sending out a
colony of this kind not only gave some satisfaction to the people, but often
established a sort of garrison, too, in a newly conquered province, of which
the obedience might otherwise have
been doubtful. A Roman colony therefore, whether we consider the nature of the
establishment itself or the motives for making it, was altogether different
from a Greek one.
Smith continued: The establishment of the European colonies
in America and the West Indies arose from no necessity and though the utility
which has resulted from them has been very great, it is not altogether so clear
and evident. It was not understood at their first establishment, and was not
the motive either of that establishment or of the discoveries which gave
occasion to it, and the nature, extent, and limits of that utility are not,
perhaps, well understood at this day.
Mr. Smith: The
Venetians took a very different view of expanding their trade and development
of wealth. What can you tell us about their activities?
Adam Smith: The Venetians, during the fourteenth and
fifteenth centuries, carried on a very advantageous commerce in spiceries, and
other East India goods, which they distributed among the other nations of
Europe. They purchased them chiefly in Egypt, at that time under the dominion
of the Mamelukes, the enemies of the Turks, of whom the Venetians were the
enemies and this union of interest, assisted by the money of Venice, formed
such a connection as gave the Venetians almost a monopoly of the trade.
The great profits of
the Venetians tempted the avidity of the Portuguese. They had been endeavou
ing, during the course of the fifteenth century, to find out by sea a way to
the countries from which the Moors brought them ivory and gold dust across the
desert.
They discovered the
Madeiras, the Canaries, the Azores, the Cape de Verde Islands, the coast of
Guinea, that of Loango, Congo, Angola, and Benguela, and, finally, the Cape of
Good Hope. They had long wished to share in the profitable traffic of the Venetians,
and this last discovery opened to them a probable prospect of doing so.
In 1497, Vasco de Gama
sailed from the port of Lisbon with a fleet of four ships, and after a
navigation of eleven months arrived upon the coast of Indostan, and thus
completed a course of discoveries which had been pursued with great steadiness,
and with very little interruption, for nearly a century together.
Some years before
this, while the expectations of Europe were in suspense about the projects of
the Portuguese, of which the success appeared yet to be doubtful, a Genoese
pilot formed the yet more daring project of sailing to the East Indies by the
West. The situation of those countries was at that time very imperfectly known
in Europe. The few European travellers who had been there had magnified the
distance, perhaps through simplicity and ignorance, what was really very great
appearing almost infinite to those who could not measure it or, perhaps, in
order to increase somewhat more the marvellous of their own adventures in visiting
regions so immensely remote from Europe.
The longer the way was
by the East, Columbus very justly concluded, the shorter it would be by the
West. He proposed, therefore, to take that way, as both the shortest and the
surest, and he had the good fortune to convince Isabella of Castile of the
probability of his project. He sailed from the port of Palos in August I490,
nearly five years before the expedition of Vasco de Garna set out from
Portugal, and, after a voyage of
between two and three months, discovered first some of the small Bahama or
Lucayan islands, and afterwards the great island of St. Domingo.
But the countries
which Columbus discovered, either in this or in any of his subsequent voyages,
had no resemblance to those which he had gone in quest of. Instead of the
wealth, cultivation, and populousness of China and Indostan, he found, in St.
Domingo, and in all the other parts of the new world which he ever visited,
nothing but a country quite covered with wood, uncultivated, and inhabited only
by some tribes of naked and miserable savages.
He was not very
willing, however, to believe that they were not the same with some of the
countries described by Marco Polo, the first European who had visited, or at
least had left behind him, any description of China or the East Indies; and a
very slight resemblance, such as that which he found between the name of Cibao,
a mountain in St. Domingo, and that of Cipango mentioned by Marco Polo, was
frequently sufficient to make him return to this favourite prepossession,
though contrary to the clearest evidence. In his letters to Ferdinand and
Isabella he called the countries which he had discovered the Indies.
He entertained no
doubt but that they were the extremity of those which had been described by Marco
Polo, and that they were not very distant from the Ganges, or from the
countries which had been conquered by Alexander. Even when at last convinced
that they were different, he still flattered himself that those rich countries
were at no great distance, and, in a subsequent voyage, accordingly, went in
quest of them along the coast of Terra Firma, and towards the Isthmus of
Darien.
Smith continued: In
consequence of this mistake of Columbus, the name of the Indies has stuck to
those unfortunate countries ever since; and when it was at last clearly
discovered that the new were altogether different from the old Indies, the
former were called the West, in contradistinction to the latter, which were
called the East Indies.
It was of importance
to Columbus, however, that the countries which he had discovered, whatever they
were, should be represented to the court of Spain as of very great consequence
and in what constitutes the real riches of every country, the animal and
vegetable productions of the soil, there was at that time nothing which could
well justify such a representation of them.
Mr. Smith: You
mentioned the riches discovered by Columbus, what where the products that
constitute those riches?
Adam Smith: The vegetable food of the inhabitants,
though from their want of industry not very abundant, was not altogether so
scanty. It consisted in Indian corn, yams, potatoes, bananas, etc., plants
which were then altogether unknown in Europe, and which have never since been
very much esteemed in it, or supposed to yield a sustenance equal to what is
drawn from the common sorts of grain and pulse, which have been cultivated in
this part of the world time out of mind.
The cotton plant,
indeed, afforded the material of a very important manufacture, and was at that
time to Europeans undoubtedly the most valuable of all the vegetable
productions of those islands. But though in the end of the fifteenth
century the muslins and other cotton goods of the East Indies were much
esteemed in every part of Europe, the cotton manufacture itself was not
cultivated in any part of it. Even this production, therefore, could not at
that time appear in the eyes of Europeans to be of very great consequence.
Finding nothing either
in the animals or vegetables of the newly discovered countries which could
justify a very advantageous representation of them, Columbus turned his view
towards their minerals and in the richness of the productions of this third
kingdom, he flattered himself he had found a full compensation for the insignificancy
of those of the other two.
The little bits of
gold with which the inhabitants ornamented their dress, and which, he was
informed, they frequently found in the rivulets and torrents that fell from the
mountains, were sufficient to satisfy him that those mountains abounded with
the richest gold mines. St. Domingo, therefore, was represented as a country
abounding with gold, and, upon that account an inexhaustible source of real
wealth to the crown and kingdom of Spain.
Mr. Martin Chekel, a noted international businessman and
author of the thought provoking “Managing America” six book series and the
retrospective eight book series “The Diary of American Foreign Policy 1938 –
1945” that laid the foundation for US foreign policy the past seventy-four
years.
No comments:
Post a Comment